As Part 2 in this series explained, the US Supreme Court could adopt a test to protect against intentional partisan gerrymandering. Such a test could prevent egregious power grabs like Wisconsin’s Republican-drawn district maps that enabled Republicans to win more than 60 percent of seats in the state house despite winning less than 49 percent of the vote.

But unintentional unfairness is the scaly underbelly of single-winner districts. For example, Washington state uses an independent redistricting commission to eliminate intentional bias, but in 2016 Republicans won 51 percent of seats in the state senate even though Democrats won 54 percent of the votes.

Partisan districtors can use district lines to “pack” and “crack” voters of one party. But it turns out voters unwittingly “pack” themselves when they move to places where they are surrounded by like-minded people. If some voters have “packed” themselves into certain geographical areas, the most disinterested computer algorithm, seeking to make compact, un-salamanderish districts, will end up disproportionately diluting those voters’ votes. Other voters’ votes will have more power to elect a representative, and the legislature will unfairly skew towards the geographically more dispersed voters.

Urban Democrats have “packed” themselves

In the United States today, left-leaning voters have packed themselves into dense urban areas. Researchers call it the “Big Sort” and “natural geographic sorting.” Journalists recognize the “two Americas.” Part of why the Supreme Court has been reticent to strike down gerrymandering is the difficulty in distinguishing intentional partisan manipulation from the “natural packing effect.”

Some research concludes that unintentional self-sorting plays a bigger role in the “persistent pro-Republican bias” in districts than intentional gerrymandering, and even when maps are drawn by courts or commissions, Republicans will still win more seats than votes. The Republican National Committee’s brief to the Supreme Court in the upcoming gerrymandering case dedicates an entire section to this point, titled: “Research confirms that the geographic distribution of Republican and Democratic Voters result in more Republican Seats irrespective of partisan gerrymandering.” It points to computer modeling showing that, in single-winner districts, geographically concentrated voters can’t win as many seats as geographically dispersed voters, even if they outnumber them.

The researchers say “as the ratio of seats to voters in a legislative body increases, it becomes more difficult for the political party whose voters are geographically concentrated to maintain statewide vote parity.” In other words, smaller single-member districts make it difficult for geographically concentrated (in dense urban areas) Democratic voters to win a fair number of seats. A Democratic-leaning state will elect a Republican-leaning legislature from single-member districts even if a non-partisan body draws the lines. (See: Washington state senate.)

Compact districts make rural voters more powerful than urban voters

Redistricting processes, including California’s well-designed independent commission, often include an explicit goal of drawing compact districts, to avoid the unsightly shapes that signal intentional gerrymandering. Sure, independent commissions or computer algorithms can draw compact districts. But, because of the “natural sorting” explained above, those compact districts will disempower voters; they will be neither competitive nor representative.

Here’s a simple thought experiment modified from the one described in this article: a state has 56 Democratic voters and 44 Republicans divided into 10 single-member districts. The state’s four urban districts vote 8-to-2 for Democratic candidates and the six suburban and rural district vote 6-to-4 for Republican candidates. Democrats have a clear majority of voters but only 40 percent of the seats—a legislature that doesn’t represent the voters. No nefarious partisan shenanigans needed—just single-member districts’ inherent flaws. Washington voters aren’t as neatly divided as this thought experiment, but the state senate shows this principle in action. Sixty percent of Republican senators won with less than 60 percent of the vote, but only 25 percent of Democratic senators did. Half of Democratic senators won with a landslide more than 70 percent of the vote. More concentrated Democratic districts allowed Republicans to win more seats than they won votes, based solely on geography and not intentional gerrymandering.

Original Sightline Institute graphic, available under our free use policy.

Safe districts make political parties and primary voters more powerful than general voters

In the example above, none of the districts are competitive. Whichever candidate wins, the party primary can just coast to victory in the general. When an incumbent is running in the primary he is almost guaranteed to win—in Oregon more than 90 percent and in Washington more than 85 percent of state house incumbents face no primary challenger. In a safe district, members of the weaker political party knows they have no chance to win, so they might not even bother running a candidate, leaving general election voters literally without any power to choose who wins. In close to 40 percent of races in Oregon and Washington, one of the two major parties doesn’t even bother running a candidate.

  • Give today to help Sightline reach our goal of $100,000!

    Thanks to Annie Breckenfeld for supporting a sustainable Cascadia.


    $77,000

  • An independent commission could instead aim to draw competitive districts where each party has a shot at winning and each candidate has to work to connect with voters. To do that, the line-drawers would have to slice and dice those cities into irregular, gerrymandered districts that clumsily concatenate a bit of the city and a chunk of suburbia. Pizza slices radiating from downtown Portland or Boise, for example, or ribbons that cross Washington from the Pacific to the Idaho border. Independent commissions are loathe to draw districts that might look at a glance to be gerrymandered, so they end up drawing districts that are just as safe for one party as do partisan line-drawers.

    Single-winner districts minimize voters within and outside the two major parties

    Measuring how many votes and how many seats each party wins doesn’t account for the voters who might prefer a different candidate within their own party or another party altogether. For example, in 2016, Libertarian candidates won 3 percent of the vote in Washington, despite the fact that single-member districts systematically exclude third parties from winning seats. Likely, more voters truly preferred a Libertarian or other third-party candidate but didn’t want to throw their vote away on a candidate doomed to lose. All those voters have less power to elect a representative they like than do voters who truly prefer a major party candidate.   

    Even within a major party, voters may differ. For example, in 2016 56 percent of voters in Washington congressional District 7 voted for Democrat Pramila Jayapal, while 44 percent voted for Democrat Brady Piñero Walkinshaw. The rough two-party analysis says 100 percent of those voters got a representative from their preferred party, but clearly one wing of the party won representation while voters from another wing may not feel as represented.

    One person, one vote

    The US Supreme Court has long upheld the principle of “one person, one vote.” This principle means districts must include roughly the same number people—otherwise, voters in a less populous district would have more power than voters in a more populous district. The Supreme Court has held that racial gerrymandering—packing African-Americans into a single district—illegally discriminates based on race by giving white voters more power than the packed African-American voters. But the Court is not likely to weigh in on the idea that single-member districts give rural voters and primary voters more power than urban voters and general election voters, but the same principle applies. Every voter should have equal power to elect someone to represent her in the legislature.

    Multi-member districts make all voters count equally

    In a district where three candidates can win seats, gerrymandering can’t disempower voters. In a district that would be completely safe for one party in a single-member system—say it leans 70 percent Democrat—conservative voters would be able to elect one of three representatives. And even the Democratic incumbent couldn’t just skate by without voters having a say because two left-leaning seats would be up for grabs, opening the race to a different kind of Democrat or even to a Social Democrat or a Green Party representative. Voters of all stripes would have equal opportunity to make their vote count in electing a representative of their choice.

    Multi-member districts give all voters a chance to elect a representative, no matter their views or their zipcode.
    Tweet This

    For example, currently, each of Washington’s 49 districts elect three state officials (a senator and two state representatives) in the three separate races, and often all three are of the same party, and even the same wing of that party. A voter in that district who prefers a different party or a different wing of the party has no one representing her views in the state legislature, even though three people represent her district. If the voter could instead elect three officials at once, she could make her voice heard as loudly as every other voter. The result in a left-leaning district might be a switch from three similar Democrats to one progressive Democrat, one standard Democrat, and one moderate Republican.

    In the 2016 race for congressional District 7, voters were forced to vote either for Pramila Jayapal or Brady Pinero Walkinshaw. But with the federal Fair Representation Act’s multi-member districts, progressive voters could have ranked Jayapal first and Walkinshaw second, while conservative voters could have voted for someone who better matched their views.   

    Multi-member districts give all voters a chance to elect a representative, no matter their views or their zipcode.

    Slaying the Gerrymander, Part 2: Make More Votes Matter